The Farmland Law stipulates that land can be legally bought and sold on
a land market with land use certificates (LUCs), thereby inaugurating a
Western-style (individual) private property rights regime that reduces
the value of land and associated natural resources to an economic
asset. Other non-economic meanings and values of land have thus been
discarded. Meanwhile, the legalisation of a land market without strong
public safeguards has opened the door to a new generation of problems.
“Under this new law, farmers who have been growing on hereditary land
for their livelihoods can only possess land by means of o cial registra-
tion. As the registration process is not easily accessible for rural people,
the land policies put them at risk. In most cases, they are helpless”.20
The Vacant, Fallow, and Virgin (VFV) Land Law allows the central govern-
ment to reallocate villagers’ farm and forestlands – both upland shifting
land, especially fallows, and lowlands without o cial land title – to
domestic and foreign investors. Community-managed resources, such
as village forests, waterways, fishponds and grazing lands are equally
susceptible to confiscation, despite being crucial to local livelihoods
and food security, particularly for vulnerable households. The law
allows for a total acreage for industrial crops for up to a maximum of
50,000 acres for a thirty-year lease, with the possibility for renewal.
These two new land laws immediately put upland communities –
composed mainly of di erent ethnic minority groups - under threat
of losing their lands, many of which were already being targeted for
resource extraction, agribusiness concessions, and mega infrastructure
projects. The new laws undermine their right to land, including their right
to decide how they will use and manage their farms and forestlands,
as well as their right to food and water, among others, while the right
of return of hundreds of thousands of IDPs, refugees and migrants
who used to occupy and use land in these areas is forestalled.
A third law designed to attract Foreign Direct Investment (FDI restricts
some sectors, including the agricultural sector, to large-scale (private)
investment, and gives land use rights of up to seventy years, with an
option to extend if the concession is located in less developed and poor
communication areas that are ‘suitable for the economic development